Panel Title: Institutions and Agricultural
Development
Convenor:R
S Deshpande, Institute for Social and Economic Change, ISEC,
Bangalore, India Co-convenor:Neelambar
Hatti, Dept of Economic History, Lund University, Sweden
Friday
9 July, 8–12 & 13–18
Panel Abstract: Institutions play
a significant role in Asian agricultural development. In south Asian
countries agricultural institutions have a long history, starting
from the traditional form of shifting cultivation to modern capital
intensive agriculture. This also poses certain questions on the
factors that have compelled such changes and transformation. Institutions
in agriculture could be analyzed in various ways. However, to organize
them in a systematic framework these can be grouped in four basic
forms namely institutions associated with inputs, production, exchange,
and social system..
Composition of inputs in agriculture has undergone drastic changes
over a period of time. During the early phases of settling cultivators
and pre-modern agriculture seeds and manual labor were the only
inputs beside some simplistic instruments for agricultural activities.
Therefore, institutions in South Asia developed often to regulate
labor and route the other inputs. However, with the advancement
of agriculture besides labor, availability of land was also scarce.
In such phases, institutions attempted to regulate both land and
labor often through interlocking them. In recent years agricultural
inputs have substantially increased from land labor to various forms
of seeds (HYV and GM), fertilizer, pesticides, insecticides, various
instruments like tractors etc.
Institutions associated with production had always two functions.
First, to enhance the productivity of the system with the improvement
in technology. Second, to reduce uncertainties associated with the
production system. Improvement in technology is often is associated
with the input structure. Various institutions emerged to regulate
the input supply and organize the production system. Such institutions
over the years however, have undergone changes: non-cultivators
became the landowners (feudal) and tillers became the tenants. There
are other forms of production institutions like production mortgage,
contracting of fruit gardens and tribal agricultural institutions.
Exchange as an integral form of market institution has undergone
changes in various forms. The economic exchange from a barter system
in a need-based economy to economic exchange in monetary units is
a substantial departure. In monetary exchanges too we identify various
deformities associated with the system. Such distress related to
exchange at a set rate by the traders, or interlocking of land market,
labor market, and product market with the credit market are some
well known facts in the political economy literature, which attributes
the development of such markets to the colonial revenue policies.
In the context of liberalisation in the World these forms have received
added attention. Therefore, the existing as well as the emerging
institutions need to be taken up for discussion and research;
• Role of Institutions in agricultural as well as overall
development scenario.
• Forms and operations of social-political and economic
institutions in various sectors
• Traditional and new emerging institutions with an emphasis
on their impact on the economy and society.
• Interlinkages of social-political and economic institutions
and their impact on the aggregate growth.
Paper Giver 1: Deepak
Shah, Faculty Member, Gokhale Institute of Politics &
Economics, BMCC Road, Deccan Gymkhana, Pune 411004 (Maharashtra),
India.
Paper 1 Title: Rural Credit
Delivery System in Maharashtra: A Step Towards Rejuvenation
Paper Abstract: An investigation into rural
credit delivery system in Maharashtra shows slower growth in institutional
finances through commercial banks, credit cooperatives, RRBs and
LDBs, particularly during the decade of 1991-2000, which is mainly
due to adverse environment created by the financial sector reforms.
Due to unfavourable policy framework, the entire rural credit delivery
system encompassing rural branches of commercial banks, cooperative
credit institutions and RRBs is reduced to a moribund state. High
transaction costs and poor repayment performance are the twin root
causes of the moribund state of rural credit delivery system. With
a view to revive the agricultural credit delivery system, there
is need to adopt innovative approaches like linking of Self-Help
Groups (SHGs) and Non-Government Organizations (NGOs) with mainstream
financial institutions. Such linkages are reported to have not only
reduced transaction costs but also ensured better repayment performance.
One of the recent studies conducted in Maharashtra has shown cent
per cent recovery of loans through SHGs despite having excessively
high rates of interest (24-36 per cent per annum) on their loan
advances. One of the further disquieting features of RFIs in Maharashtra
has been the high proportion of NPAs to total assets, particularly
of RRBs and SCARDBs, which are estimated to hover around 36-48 per
cent during the mid-to late nineties. One of the reasons for such
high incidence of NPAs of RFIs has been the familiar practice of
debt forgiveness, which eroded repayment and allowed defaulters
to scot free with no deterrent reprimand. Political interference
in issues of prudent fiscal management has got a lot to do with
this unfortunate scenario. In order to rejuvenate rural credit delivery
system, the twin problems facing the system, viz., high transaction
costs and poor repayment performance, need to be tackled with more
fiscal jurisprudence reserving exemplary punishment for willful
defaults, especially by large farmers. In fact, insofar as the rural
credit delivery system is concerned, the focus should be on strategies
that are required for tackling issues such as sustainability and
viability, operational efficiency, recovery performance, small farmer
coverage and balanced sectoral development.
Paper Giver 2: R.
Parthasarathy, Professor, Gujarat Institute of Development Research,
Gota, Ahmedabad, India
Paper 2 Title: New Institutions
in Irrigation Sector: Their Trajectories and Impact on Rural Economy
Paper Abstract: Since the mid-1980s, governments
worldwide have been engaged in Irrigation Management Transfer (IMT)
in one form or other. Managerial and financial responsibilities
for the public schemes are being handed over to newly organized
Water User Associations (WUAs), with a view to improve water rights
of farmers and improvising the use efficiency of the infrastructure.
The goals were three-fold. First, IMT was expected to boost productivity
by harnessing farmers local knowledge, entrepreneurial skills
and their interest in ensuring adequate water services. Implicitly
it was expected that though participatory irrigation management
is, not a panacea for all water management issues, it could go a
long way in ensuring efficient running of canals, optimum on-field
water application and reuse or proper drainage of the excess water
from irrigation systems and farmers fields. Second, the accompanying
reform of mostly-inefficient yet costly state irrigation bureaucracies
was supposed to lead to better water services and, lastly, to promote
participation management which would then lead to users managing
the systems. Overtime, however, the goals have become much less
ambitious. Presently, IMT is considered successful if it saves government
money, improves cost-effectiveness of operation and maintenance
while improving, or at least not weakening the productivity of irrigated
agriculture. The results of the documentation of the process of
implementation and evaluation of PIM programmes indicate dwindling
expectations. Productivity gains are hardly reported. Recent evaluations
of past IMT programmes show a clear trade-off between past modes
of IMT and poverty alleviation. Earlier, it was assumed that IMT
is class neutral. However, the mode of IMT, as implemented till
now, appears to work only in non-poor, high-performing, business-like
agriculture In schemes in the middle- and low-income countries with
a heterogeneous composition of farmers in the command areas, IMT
could only succeed where farmers with the largest holdings became
the champions. In some places, withdrawal of state support
has led to partial or full collapse of the scheme, with negative
consequences for productivity. The paper argues that IMT could have
been successful if the process had been right, that is, if it had
been more gradual, with more emphasis on institutions. This would
have led to a better definition of water rights. These and other
factors have also impacted on the extent of participation of users
in the newly set up programme; some would argue that extent of participation
has also impacted the expected results of the IMT programme.
Paper Giver 3: Thijs
Wissink, Nijmegen University, Netherlands
Paper 3 Title: The impact
of trade liberalisation on agriculture in Bhutan
Paper Abstract: Bhutan is in the process of
accession to the WTO and also takes part in the SAFTA (South Asian
Free Trade Agreement). Bhutan is one of the most mountainous countries
in the world, which has big implications for its agriculture, both
in terms of production as well as in terms of the marketing of its
products. Generally spoken, productivity is relatively low compared
to its neighbouring countries and that brings up the question whether
its agriculture will be able to compete with the cheaper imports,
which generally come along with trade liberalisation. However, further
trade liberalisation is not likely to effect Bhutanese agriculture
substantively, as its agricultural markets has been practically
liberalised since 1949, when the country signed a free trade agreement
with its big neighbour India. Bhutan started opening up to outside
world from nineteen sixties, when it became a member of the UN and
when the first roads were built. Since its agriculture started slowly
developing from complete subsistence oriented, towards more market
oriented, it did not face much protection, besides the countrys
topography and small market, which adds considerable transport costs
to everything imported. The fact that Bhutanese agriculture has
its current low productivity level, is partly a consequence of the
absence of adequate protection of its agricultural markets. Other
factors are the unfavourable natural environment, its poor production
and marketing infrastructure and the slow pace of modernisation
by farmers. Bhutanese agriculture is not fully taking advantage
of the market offered by its growing urban population. Despite the
fact that Bhutanese consumers prefer domestically produced agricultural
products, only a part of the consumers is willing to pay the price,
which is relatively high compared to Indian import products. However,
to generate more cash income, Bhutanese farmers have adopted cultivation
of various cash crops, which are exported, mostly to India and Bangladesh.
The most important cash crops are mandarins, apples and potatoes,
for which production the country obviously has a comparative advantage.
For a country with one of the highest percentages of rural population,
it is extremely important to raise rural incomes. Agricultural development
will stimulate general economic development in many ways. To ensure
this the country should put more effort to strengthen its current
agricultural export markets. It could profit even much more from
its comparative advantage for these crops, if it would improve the
marketing and production. Secondly it should stimulate the production
and marketing of the domestically consumed products and force import
substitution. Finally it should identify new potential export products,
for export to neighbouring countries, as well as Western countries.
These products should be high value niche products. The country
has comparative advantages for these kinds of products, lying in
its exceptional environmental circumstances and the relatively clean
production (low use of agrochemicals). Niche products to be identified
could lie in the range of medicinal plants, organically produced
products, floricultural products, incense and mushrooms. To make
a success out of these products, very professional efforts should
be made, again both in terms of production and marketing.
Paper Giver 4:Steen
Folke, Danish Institute for International Studies, Copenhagen,
Denmark
Paper 4 Title: From Training
and Visit Extension to Farm Women Groups: Impact in terms
of economic benefits and empowerment of four Danida-supported
training projects for farm women
Paper Abstract: Since around 1980 agricultural
extension in India has been dominated by the Training and Visit
approach initially propagated by the World Bank. The approach has
been criticised for its rather top-down communication, individual
focus on contact farmers and narrow and standardised extension messages.
From the mid-1990s more broad-based, group-focused and participatory
approaches to agricultural extension have gradually replaced the
T&V system. This evolution is also reflected in the history
of four Danida-supported training projects for farm women, three
of which were initiated in the 1980s. The projects are Women and
Youth Training and Extension Project, WYTEP, in Karnataka (1982-2005),
Tamil Nadu Women in Agriculture, TANWA (1986-2003), Training and
Extension for Women in Agriculture, TEWA, in Orissa (1987-2003)
and Madhya Pradesh Women in Agriculture, MAPWA (1993-2005). These
projects have been innovative in so far as they have for the first
time on a major scale targeted women in their role as agricultural
producers. Over the years more than 1 million farm women have received
training and extension under the four projects, mostly based on
the T&V approach, but in recent years with Farm Women Groups
as the framework for both extension and income generating activities.
The total cost for Danish tax payers has been around DKK 279 million.
Based on extensive fieldwork in all four states (in 2002-03) by
a team of researchers and research assistants (in the context of
a Danida evaluation for which the author was team leader) the paper
investigates the impact of the four projects both in terms of economic
benefits (higher yields, savings on chemical fertilizers, income
generating activities) and their contribution to the farm womens
empowerment (self confidence, role in decision making, collective
strength). The analysis uses the empowerment framework developed
by Naila Kabeer, who was a member of the team. The impact is analysed
in relation to the institutions involved, particularly T&V versus
the Farm Women Groups, and the village-based training employed by
three of the projects versus training in district agricultural centres
employed by the oldest and biggest project, WYTEP.
Paper Giver 5: R.V.Dadibhavi
, Professor, Dept of Economics, Karnatak University, Dharwad, India.
Paper 5 Title: Institutions for Management
of Common Property
Paper Abstract: It is well known that the growth of Indian
agricultural sector has suffered a heavy toll in the post-economic
reform period that began in the mid 1991.Several studies revealed
that price and non-price factors such as technology, production-cum
market infrastructure and conducive institutional structure, both
formal and informal, are more potent besides being relatively more
important in influencing agricultural development in India. In the
new policy regime, the emphasis shifted to greater role of markets
in economic development and the receding role of the state. A study
visualized continued dominance of the state in irrigation and extension
and infrastructure development, but he underlined the need for reforms
in the public organizations for their financial viability and efficiency.
However some researchers consider institutional reforms sine qua
non for sustainable agricultural development and poverty alleviation.
In particular, sustainable use of common pool resources and management
of surface irrigation have received much greater attention and the
need for institutional reforms ensuring stake holders participation
and equitable distribution of benefits is reiterated time and again.
In this paper, we use the available evidence and also present our
micro level study evidences to draw lessons for the development
of commons requiring collective actions. Open access to the commons
is the main problem which is popularly known as the tragedy
of commons. Commercialization of resources and conflicts arising
due to increasing scarcity have further complicated the management
problem. Besides these problems distorted policies, breakdown of
traditional social institutions and lack of alternative institutions
are responsible for the degradation of the commons. Similarly breakdown
of village level social institutions led to degradation of common
lands, irrigation tanks and village forests, etc. The objectives
of the study are: To examine changing size of CPR;s in Karnataka;
ii. to study status of common property land resources; iii. to examine
the impact of CPR on the livestock economy.; iv. to study the contributions
of CPRs to rural households in Karnataka. The study is based
on both Primary and Secondary level data. Primary level data are
collected through sample household survey of 1021 poor and 347 non-poor
households in 15 villages, spread in four regions of Karnataka state
in India during June 1994 to July 1995. The main findings of the
study are: i. CPRs in land has declined over the last 30 years;
ii. Animal husbandry is an inseparable complementary activity in
Karnataka and this activity is directly dependent upon the availability
of CPRs; iii. Illegal encroachment is responsible for loss
of CPRs in villages.; CPRs contribution to the rural
household even today is significant to both poor and non-poor in
regard to the fuel and fodder requirement, income and employment.
The emerging policy implications of the study are: i. There is need
to discontinue the policy of government distribution of grazing
land and waste land to the poor for cultivation and to the private
parties. ii. The effective management of CPRs cannot be thought
of without the emergence of strong local institutions.; iii. Community
management of commons must be encouraged.; iii. The study shows
that it is inescapable for government, village community and NGOs
to play a crucial role in overcoming the problems of the tragedy
of commons.
Paper Giver 6: Jatinder
Bir Singh, Reader in Economics, SGGS College of Commerce, University
of Delhi, India
Paper 6 Title: Futures Markets and Price
Stabilization - Evidence from Indian Hessian Market
Paper Abstract: Futures markets play important role in determining
the inventory decisions in the cash market. The futures market is
the nerve centre for collection and dissemination of information
about the agents expectations of future cash market. It performs
the price insurance and price discovery functions. The latter function
enables the traders to make rational choices about inventory management.
This results in reduction in volatility of cash prices. This paper
investigates the hessian cash (spot) price variability before and
after (over 1988-1997 period) the introduction of futures trading
to ascertain whether the futures market help in reducing the intra-seasonal
and/or inter-seasonal price fluctuations. This paper is seeking
to show how the influence of hessian futures market has led to reduced
cash market volatility in the hessian market.To know about the pattern
of volatility over the season, Figlewisky (1981) measure of volatility
has been adopted. To take account of inter-seasonal price variability,
this volatility measure has been normalized to make it akin to coefficient
of variation. The relationship between hessian price variability
and jute prices has been investigated using regression of logarithm
of volatility on logarithm of prices and monthly dummy variables.
To take account of possible price variation differences between
the two sub-periods, multiplicative dummy variable model was applied.The
evidence in this paper suggests that cash market volatility was
less pronounced after 1992 when hessian futures market was established.
The major role for futures market appears to be in reducing inter-seasonal
volatility as opposed to intra-seasonal volatility. The results
suggest that futures market may be indeed viable policy alternative
for policy-makers to reduce uncertainty in agricultural markets.
The liberalization of state support policy which was designed to
stabilize farmers income will increase risk and uncertainty
to market participants. The futures markets through its information
role may vastly improve the storage across the seasons, thereby
stabilizing cash prices.
Paper Giver 7: Balz
Strasser, Research Assistant, Department of Geography, University
of Zurich, Switzerland
Paper 7 Title: Rubber small-holders in
Kerala
Paper Abstract: In recent years, the Indian natural rubber
sector has been affected by trends towards trade liberalisation,
a reduced role of the state, and organisational reforms. Rubber
small-holders in Kerala have been affected by these processes in
different ways. It is hypothesised that small producers, especially
the ones located in agro-ecologically marginal rubber areas, are
nowadays coping these changes with attempts to move from rubber-dominated
to more diversified livelihood strategies. Using empirical case
study material, a detailed analysis of recent changes of livelihood
strategies of different categories of small-holders will be presented.
A special focus will be given to the analysis of the wider institutional
setting within which small-holders operate, e.g. markets, trade
unions, extension services, etc., trying to assess its supportive
or hindering role in the diversification process.
Paper Giver 8: Kumbamu
Ashok, Research Scholar, Department of Sociology, National University
of Singapore
Paper 8 Title: The Gene Revolution
in the Era of Globalization: Changing Agra
Paper Abstract: In the early 1960s, the Green Revolution
package comprising the miracle seeds, controlled irrigation,
fertilizers, pesticides, and correlated farm management skills has
been introduced into the post-colonial societies with the premise
of averting the Malthusian spectre of famine. But despite the profound
impact of the Green Revolution on food grain production,
(FAO, 2001 estimates) over 800 million people are still suffering
from permanent or intermittent hunger and about 2 billion people
are chronically undernourished. More than 150 million children under
the age of 5 years are underweight and about 6 million children
in the Third World die each year due to malnourishment. Since the
problem of feeding the worlds rapidly growing population has
not been solved through the Green Revolution technological
interventions, now, the war on hunger is being waged
by using the cutting-edge technologies in molecular and cell biology,
which are often discussed under the general rubric of biotechnology
or the Gene Revolution. The experience of the Green
Revolution in India shows that besides the technological advancements
and applications; institutional support such as credit, extension
services, land reforms etc., played a paramount role in increasing
agricultural production at the national level. The past experiences
in Indian agriculture also show that the potentials of the technological
application could not be realized due to lack of proper instructional
support. Indeed, agrarian institutions have very important role
to play in the era of the Gene Revolution since (a)
the new technologies are knowledge/information-intensive and the
cost of imperfect information in terms of yield or production loss
is very high; (b) the new seeds increase pressure on cash-needs
of the peasantry; and (c) inadequate vigilant regulatory mechanism
to control selling of spurious seeds may devastate entire crops,
which may result in negative externalities and collective actions.The
proponents of biotechnology often claim that the Gene Revolution
is a prolongation of the Green Revolution or the Doubly
Green Revolution or the Evergreen Revolution,
and the new technology is neutral and the benefits could
be more widespread to all regions. They further argue that to realize
the potentiality of the new agricultural technologies of the Gene
Revolution, efficient agrarian institutions would be required.
Contrary to the enthusiastic claims of the proponents, the opponents
of the Gene Revolution, by considering the terminator
and gene-pesticide character of the new seeds, argue
that biotechnology has profound implications for millions of poor
farmers and environment in the Third World, whether or not there
is proper institutional support. However, the institutional division
between basic research (public research) and applied
research (private research) , overwhelming involvement of
private sector in research, development and marketing of the new
seeds, extension of patents to living organisms (genes in particular)
under the new trade regime, commoditization of seeds, rapid adoption
of genetically modified crops by farmers across the globe and possible
adverse consequences of biotechnology have become the central issues
in the raging global debate about biotechnology. However, biotechnology
is an innovative technology, which offers many possibilities for
development and application. The consequences - opportunities and
risks - involved are remain uncertain. The central problem is therefore
the uncertainty of knowledge. This uncertainty also applies to the
question of whether biotechnology conforms to the overall concept
of sustainable development. Therefore understanding the potential
benefits and risks of biotechnology going beyond the narrow economic
cost/benefit analysis and gauging its relevance to rural development
in India is very essential. However, the contemporary issues pertaining
to agricultural biotechnology can be adequately understood only
when viewed in a socio-historical perspective. Thus the paper attempts
to analyze the political and economic history of development of
biotechnology and the importance of agrarian institutions in the
era of globalization and biotechnology. In so doing, the paper is
structured as follows: (i) conceptual and theoretical aspects of
the development of the new agricultural technologies in general,
and biotechnology in particular; (ii) transition from the Green
Revolution to the Gene Revolution and its implication
for agrarian change in India; (iii) the implications of institutional
reforms in the milieu of liberalization and the Gene Revolution
for the Indian peasantry, research and development and domestic
seed industry; and (iv) finally, it addresses the need of the new
agrarian institutions in the ear of capitalist globalization and
biotechnology.
Paper Giver 9: A.
Narayanamoorthy, Reader, Gokhale Institute of Politics and Economics,
Pune, India, and R S Deshpande,
Institute for Social and Economic Change, ISEC, Bangalore, India
Paper 9 Title: Irrigation Institutions
in India: With Special Reference to Maharashtra State
Paper Abstract: Role of institutions (Water Users
Associations) in water management is not a new phenomenon as far
as India is concerned. In the name of kudimaramat, the users (farmers)
were involved in tank repairs, management works, distilling of tanks,
removal of weeds, distribution of water and collecting revenue even
during the 17th and 18th century much before the British rule. Unfortunately,
due to various reasons, the users participation in water management
has declined drastically over the years. Now, partly because of
pressure from the donor agencies such as the World Bank, the users
participation in irrigation water management has become a widespread
strategy in all countries in Asia including India. In India, more
emphasis was given to users participation in water management
only after the announcement of the National Water Policy: 1987 &
2002, wherein gradual involvement of farmers in system management
was advocated. Studies carried out in different countries including
India have clearly established that users-managed systems outperformed
the systems that are managed by the irrigation agencies. While the
irrigated area managed by the Water Users Associations (WUAs)
is very limited as of today in India, a significant progress has
been made, at the policy level, in bringing more irrigation systems
under WUAs in the recent years. In Maharashtra, significant progress
has taken place since 1992 as the irrigation department has been
encouraging the farmers to form WUAs by explaining its advantages.
As a result of the continuous effort by the irrigation department
and non-governmental organisations, about 822 WUAs have been functioning
at different levels in Maharashtra as of September 2001. While there
are no two opinions about the importance of WUAs in increasing the
performance of irrigation system, there is no guarantee that WUAs
would improve the performance of irrigation system, as the interference
of government agencies is still considerable. It is also reported
that the most part the outlet and canal committees are there only
in name; they are not consulted on substantive issues; nor are department
officers required to follow their advice. There is also considerable
reluctance, if not opposition, from the operational staff of irrigation
departments to involving users in management; and even users themselves
tend to be apathetic to the idea. However, not many studies have
analysed how the new (WUAs) irrigation institutions established
with the support of government agencies are functioning at the field
and whether WUAs are able to fulfill the objectives for which the
same is established. It is in this context, an attempt will be made
in this study to bring out the overall functioning of different
irrigation institutions (lift irrigation users association,
canal irrigation users association, etc) using both primary
and secondary level information.
Paper Giver 10: Amalendu
Jyotishi, Assistant Professor, Gujarat Institute of Development
Research, Ahmedabad, India, R
S Deshpande, Institute for Social and Economic Change, ISEC,
Bangalore, India, and Neelambar
Hatti, Dept of Economic History, Lund University, Sweden
Paper 10 Title: Institutions and Poverty
Paper Abstract: The two-fold role of the Indian State as
a development catalyst and as an interventionist has long been debated
on the count of ease in policy formulation. Institutions in various
forms have been constantly shaping the policy from the outside State
ambit. On this backdrop the present paper addresses to the analysis
of the role of the State as reflected from the nexus between the
State policies, interest groups and institutions to reach the consequent
steps towards alleviation of poverty. It is pointed out that the
role of state in India has changed substantially during the last
five decades in perceiving poverty and this is largely due to the
institutional interface. The results show positive success during
seventies till mid eighties and stagnation thereafter. The paper
incorporates discussion on the differential policy impact in a federal
context, on different provinces of the Indian federation and the
differential changes in poverty across groups, specifically the
rural population and the weaker sections of the society. The paper
highlights the role of institutions in the poverty alleviation strategy
Paper Giver 11: Vinod
Vyasulu, Centre for Budget and Policy Research, Basavanagudi,
Bangalore, India
Paper 11 Title: Agriculture and 73rd Constitutional
Amendment: Institutional Challenges
Paper Abstract:The Department of Agriculture in a state
government has been responsible for the implementation of agricultural
policy. Agriculture is a state subject in India, and although the
union government does a great deal by way of support to agricultural
research, it is the state that is responsible for the state of agriculture.
In many states, the department has risen to the challenge of improving
the lot of a largely poor farming community. At the government level
is a minister, assisted by a Secretary, who belongs to the IAS.
This ministry is responsible to the legislature for all policy matters.
For implementation, there is a Department of Agriculture headed
by a Director of Agriculture, who is a technical person. In some
states, a Commissioner for Agriculture, from the IAS, has been brough
in above the Director, but the technical nature of the department
has been retained. The Department has several divisions in the head
office, and at the district, is headed by a Joint Dorector for Agriculture,
who reports both to his department, and the deputy commissioner
or collector of the district. The collector is the head of all departments
at the district level. The JDA is helped by Assistant directors
at the block level and lower level staff at the village levels where
the interface with the farmers is highest. The 73rd amendment has
brought in elected governments at the district, block and village
levels. The department has now to function differently, but this
change has been slow in coming. This paper discusses the issues
and challenges involved in this process.
Paper Giver 12: D.V. Gopalappa
, Asst. Professor at the Institute for Social and Economic Change,
Nagarabhavi, Bangalore, India
Paper 12 Title: Institutions And Rural
Development A Case Of Sericulture Quality Clubs
Paper Abstract:The development of the rural poor is an essential
issue for the countrys equitable and sustainable economic
development. The experience so far, has been that the economic development
of the weaker sections was not possible through the government intervention
alone. Other alternatives are: actively involving people to form
co-operatives and the involvement of Non-Government Organisations,
banks, educational institutions, panchayat raj institutions, etc.
In this paper, an effort has been made to analyse the role of farmers
cooperative society in the form of a group called Sericulture Quality
Clubs (SQCs) in the rural development in general and the sericulture
activity in particular. Towards this we have taken two villages
where the SQCs are formed and implemented certain development activities
in both the villages. The empirical evidence reveals that farmers
who possess basic education in the villages have better coordination
than farmers who are illiterates and little above this standard.
Kuruburu village has been successful in its attempt to form the
society and make it as a successful programme. In approximately
two years the society with the able guidance of the president, secretary
and the members could make business of Rs 2.3 lakhs just with the
initial capital of Rs10,000 supported by the sericulture department.
Out of this they could make a profit of Rs 26,000 just by selling
the disinfectants. More than these, they could invite the scientists
and arrange the lectures, which helped them to take up the improved
varieties of mulberry and silkworm races. Whereas, in Nayakarahalli
the president and the members are not educated. The president has
studied only till the 7th standard and all the other members are
not educated and not that active. They keep quiet and do not question
the president about the initial capital and also what happens in
society. This has led to no improvement and most of the villagers
do not know whether there is a society of this kind in their own
village. The president does not like to interact with the people
easily. Therefore, this has resulted in the stagnation of yield
level in Nayakarahalli. However, it can be suggested that societies
of this kind have to be encouraged for specific programmes. But
one should select the better group with better education so that
it is easy to convince them to take up modern implements and practices
in agriculture, sericulture and other allied activities.
Paper Giver 13: Golam Rasul
and Gopal B. Thapa, School of Environment,
Resources and Development, Asian Institute of Technology, Thailand
Paper 13 Title: Implications of Changing
National Policies on Land Use in Chittagong Hill Tracts of Bangladesh
Paper Abstract: Land use in the Chittagong Hill Tracts (CHT)
of Bangladesh had undergone changes over past several centuries.
The landscape, which was mostly covered with forest with interspersed
shifting cultivation plots until the beginning of the colonial period,
had gradually changed into a landscape with a blend of land uses.
Overall, the forest area was gradually declining, while the area
under shifting cultivation and other types of sedentary agriculture
had expanded. The process of the change was multi-directional. National
forestry, land use, land taxation and population migration polices,
and development activities, such as construction of a hydroelectric
dam and roads, played an important role in this process. Shifting
cultivation had inflicted little damage on the forest until the
beginning of the colonial period. The pace of deforestation accelerated
with the nationalization of forest that abolished tribal peoples
customary use and management rights to forest, and allowed large
scale commercial logging both legally and illegally. The pace was
further intensified by the policy, encouraging population migration
to CHT and construction of a reservoir on Karnafuli River. Efforts
were made to replace shifting cultivation with more productive type
of sedentary agriculture. However, much change could not take place
in the absence of secure land rights, supportive trade policies,
and required support services and facilities, including infrastructure.
Locationally suitable land use had evolved in areas where transportation
facilities were available and farmers were granted land title with
necessary extension services and credit facility. These findings
bear important policy implications for promotion of environmentally
and economically sound land use in CHT.
Paper Giver 14:Koichi
Fujita, Associate Professor, Center for Southeast Asian Studies,
Kyoto University, Japan
Paper 14 Title: Transformation of Groundwater
Market in Bengal: Implications to Efficiency and Income Distribution
Paper Abstract: The rapid agricultural growth since the
early 1980s experienced in Bengal brought about a drastic rural
change and reduction of poverty in the region. The engine of growth
was the diffusion of private shallow tubewells (STWs). The development
of groundwater market enabled non-STW owner farmers to adopt irrigated
farming. Discussions on groundwater market have been widely done
in Bengal and other South Asian regions. Since groundwater market
is characterized as a highly segmented market, where usually a few
rich farmers sell water to a large number of poorer farmers, its
implication to income distribution has been paid serious attentions.
Efficiency issues have also been addressed, where land productivity
differential between owners and non-owner farmers has been one of
the most important issues. However, so far, empirical studies have
been, by and large, concentrated in examining the market structure
at one particular point of time. Dynamic transformation of it has
been relatively neglected. The purpose of this paper is to examine
such an aspect of groundwater market, based on primary data collected
in several selected villages in Bengal, where the author conducted
intensive surveys during the last decade. The major conclusions
are as follows.
First, in the study areas of Bengal, private STWs diffused rapidly
during the 1980s. Groundwater irrigation by tubewells covered almost
all the farmland within a decade or so, by the beginning of the
1990s. At this initial stage, tubewell owners, most of them were
large farmers, rented land from non-owner farmers on a seasonal
basis (land rent was paid in-kind after harvest), or sold water
to them under the crop-sharing arrangement with water. Under these
arrangements, the effective rate of water charge was very high,
and tubewell owners enjoyed a high rate of return. The share to
water in irrigated rice (boro) production reached as high as 30%,
and accordingly the share to land decreased to 20%, from 30-50%
in the case of traditional rainy season rice (aman). It is difficult
to deny the argument of emergence of waterlords instead
of traditional landlords.
Second, however, what happened in the 1990s was the continuous investment
in STWs even though groundwater market had already saturated.
The number of STWs reached nearly or more than double during the
several years. This resulted in a drastic decrease of command area
of tubewells (from 10-12 acres to 6-7 acres) and a substantial decline
of real water price. As a result, the rate of return declined sharply.
The share to water in irrigated rice production also decreased sharply
to 11-13% from about 30% just several years ago. The waterlords,
once appeared in the 1980s, quickly left rural Bengal by the end
of the 90s.
Third, in 1999 or 2000 there observed a sharp contrast between Bangladesh
and West Bengal in the factor share to land and labor in rice production.
Namely, the share to land reached 50-58% in Bangladesh whereas it
remained only 27-40% in West Bengal. The corresponding share to
labor was 20-30% in Bangladesh compared to 38-42% in West Bengal.
In other words, the decreased share of water in irrigated rice production
was almost totally absorbed by land in Bangladesh, while labor share
remained at a very low level.
Fourth, many STWs fell into financial deficit in both regions in
the year 1999 or 2000. However, it may not be able to say that individual
farmers who additionally invested in STWs behaved irrationally,
if various benefits from the ownership of tubewells, including non-monetary
advantages, are taken into account. It is important to note here
that there is a significant differential in land productivity between
tubewell owners and non-owner farmers. In addition, in the case
of West Bengal, groundwater market was not in equilibrium, where
conversion from ordinary STWs to submergible STWs (SMs) was going
on.
Fifth, the fact that individual farmers behave rationally
does not necessarily mean that the groundwater market is efficiently
working. Rather, it can be evaluated as inefficient, due to the
morale hazard behavior of both water sellers and buyers. Water sellers
are not conscious enough in delivering water to buyers in time and
in proper volume, while water buyers have a strong tendency to refuse
payment of water charge. Such a morale hazard behavior in both parties
strengthens each other, forming a vicious circle. Such a structure
became the main cause of the above-mentioned differential in land
productivity, which induced socially excess investment in STWs.
Sixth, policy for promoting competition among tubewells through
increased number of them in a confined area is effective to reduce
water price and thus to improve rural income distribution, but at
the same time, such a policy can easily bring about socially excess
investment in tubewells, leading to a wasteful resource use, especially
in the context of Bengal rural society.
Lastly, the introduction of SMs in West Bengal is not a fundamental
solution to the problem of declining water table. Market is not
enough to solve the problem and needs to be supplemented by some
kind of community level coordination and government regulation.
The same is the above- mentioned problem of inefficient resource
use arising from excess investment in tubewells. The transfer of
DTWs from the state government to farmers group now under
progress in West Bengal also needs some non-market institutional
mechanism. It is true that because of the individual farmers
initiative groundwater irrigation (especially STWs) achieved a widespread
and rapid progress and contributed to the agricultural development
in Bengal since the 1980s. However, it is high time to re-evaluate
the role of the government and the community in minor irrigation
sector.
Paper Giver 15: M
N Panini, Professor, Jawaharlal Nehru University, New Delhi,
India
Paper 15 Title: A Study of Social Implications
of the Introduction of Genetically Modified (GMO) Crops in Indian
Agriculture
Paper Abstract: Green revolution has dramatically turned
around India from being a country of endemic food shortages to a
country self-sufficient in food grains. The controversy about the
introduction of the GMOs has been keeping the debate alive. While
there are reports of farmers in Gujarat already cultivating Bt cotton
extensively, formal approvals for the commercial sale of genetically
modified seeds of Bt cotton and of potatoes have not been granted
as yet. The Bt cotton crop has been developed by one of worlds
major agribusiness firms Monsanto in collaboration with the Indian
firm Mahyco whereas genetically modified potato has been developed
by an Indian scientist. There is a need to study the implications
of this controversy on the State functioning, public corporations,
professionals working in the area of bio-technology, NGOs and the
farmers themselves In India the problem has become more acute because
the Indian farmers recklessly used fertilisers and pesticides by
falsely correlating productivity with the application of fertilisers
and pesticides. The proponents of biotechnology, who include some
leading biotechnologists within the country and abroad and the trans-national
agribusiness corporations that have heavily invested in research
on GMOs, hold that the new genetically modified crops reduce both
biotic and a-biotic stresses in agriculture. They claim that the
GMOs can reduce the consumption of pesticides, increase yields,
improve the ability of plants to resist droughts and enhance the
nutritional quality of food. This paper seeks to assess the social
and cultural implications of the controversy over GMOs in India.
The politics that has emerged around the introduction of GMOs in
India only serves to highlight the changed social significance of
science and technology. A dramatic example of this is the introduction
of green revolution technology in the 1960s just when
India was experiencing a major food shortage. The new agricultural
technology neatly skirted the problem of major institutional reforms
that many thinkers felt were necessary in order for India to become
a self-sufficient in food. The new technology has had a profound
impact on the Indian rural society and the rural landscape. That
food security will be ensured.
Biotechnologists have produced transgenic crops that reduce dependence
on pesticides, enhance nutritive qualities of food, increase yield
and resist droughts. They claim that transgenic crops increase productivity
and reduce ecological stress; farmers will not have to use pesticides
and fertilizers thereby increasing productivity. This development
is not even a decade old found in the genes of species of d in plants
from issue of introduction of genetically modified organisms (GMOs)
in Indian agriculture has now become a major controversy. The controversy
has been stirred by several NGOs who have vehemently opposed the
introduction of GMOs. Biotechnology promises self sufficiency for
developing countries despite prospective population increases and
minimises ecological stresses. Vigorous opposition to biotechnologyfood
developed by biotechnology is referred to as Frankenstein food.
The international patent regime, the big biotechnology corporations,
government regulations on the transgenic varieties, NGOs and the
WTO agreements intermesh to determine whether the potentials of
biotechnology are realised. This study attempts to examine the working
of the regulatory institutions in Bt cotton. It also looks into
the methodology of extension of the new technology and to study
how it affects the attitude of the farmers towards the new technology.
Apart from these how have the campaigns against Bt cotton affected
the farmers? Do they resist the technology? Who are the farmers
who have agreed to cultivate Bt cotton on their fields? Are there
any farmers who are opposing Bt cotton? What are their grounds for
opposing Bt cotton?, are some of the questions of interest addressed
in this study.
Paper Giver 16:Dr.
A. Rajagopal, Research Fellow, National Institute of Rural Development
(NIRD), Hyderabad, India
Paper 16 Title: Dynamics of Water
Institutions and Agriculture under a South Indian Canal Irrigation
System
Paper Abstract: The paper is about the water insecurity
situation in an irrigation system, factors contributing to the scarcity
condition, the role of institutions in reducing water insecurity
and its impact of agriculture and livelihoods of poor. The paper
also analyses the dynamics of these institutions over a period and
their impact on agriculture and livelihoods. These observations
are based on a study of a canal irrigation system in South India
in 1980s and a re survey of it after a period of 15 years. The study
rests on the premise that irrigation institutions and their role
in management are significantly conditioned by the agricultural
and socio-economic environment especially caste and class of the
region. Maintenance of irrigation structures and regulation of water
supply to tanks under large-scale irrigation system is fully the
responsibility of the State. However the State is not able to undertake
these functions efficiently due to its own constraints. Hence local
level irrigation organisations undertake maintenance like cleaning
and de silting of channels, which bring water to their tanks. Though
the State is not able to regulate water to the tanks properly, local
institutions themselves undertake such tasks. Collective action
both in the appropriation of water from the main canal and allocation
of water at the local / tank level is quite significant. These organizations
called panchayat have well defined structures, rules and functionaries.
The members of the panchayat are generally farmers with relatively
larger land holdings and community influence in the village. They
are assisted by professional watermen and watchmen, appointed during
every irrigation season and paid through the farmers' contribution.
Thus collective action as regards functions of water management
is quite significant and brought substantial benefits to farmers
including small in terms of access to water and productivity gains
from irrigation.
Had there not been such institutional arrangements there would have
been substantial losses to farmers (especially poor) because of
overall reduction in the quantum of water in the system due to the
inter-state river water dispute and the increased problems due to
encroachment and alkalinity of soils.Though there has been a significant
change in the land control, the villagers continue to show interest
in collective action as majority of their livelihood depends upon
agriculture for which irrigation is the basis. Not only irrigation
but also the very life of villagers depends upon cooperation among
themselves for the fear of subordination by the dominant castes.
The continued presence of irrigation institutions and their role
in water management and other village affairs point to the fact
that pessimism expressed on collective action by theorists of `tragedy
of commons' like Hardin, and Gordon is exaggerated.The resurvey
shows that irrigation systems do not exist as blue prints but continue
to undergo changes in which institutions are important. Though there
are many changes in irrigation and agriculture, caste as an institution
continues to play an important role in irrigation and other village
affairs.
SASNET - Swedish South Asian Studies Network/Lund
University
Address: Scheelevägen 15 D, SE-223 70 Lund, Sweden
Phone: +46 46 222 73 40
Webmaster: Lars Eklund
Last updated
2006-01-27